On the night of George
Osbourne’s budget, James Purnell said that the government would ‘need to raise
taxes a lot more than they’re doing’ in order to pay for the things that many
people feel ought to be done: universal welfare provision, NHS, foreign aid and
carbon reduction targets (Purnell 2012). This raises an interesting question:
do people care enough to pay? Adam Dinham, Director of the Faiths & Civil
Society Unit, recently said to me in an email that he felt welfare had become
‘a sacred totem’ (Dinham 2012). In
this short piece I reflect on how and whether these ideas and institutions
could become sacred, and what the implications for policy.
Let’s begin by putting some
parameters around the sacred. In my piece entitled What Counts as Sacred?,
I introduced Scott Atran’s notion of the sacred as ‘that which is
believed in for non-instrumental reasons’ (Stacey 2012). What I did not mention
there, but which is most poignant here, is that according to Atran a sacred
belief is reinforced, indeed rendered more trenchant, if the beholder is asked
to give up that belief in the face of a material cost or benefit (Atran 2010).
While he does not explore exactly why this is the case, it is implicit that the
very idea of something’s being sacred demands that one pay heed to it by
enduring any cost and forgoing any reward. Of course also implicit is the idea
that if something is not sacred, not much cost or benefit will be endured or
desisted
The idea of extending what
counts as sacred to areas of public policy is not unprecedented. Atran himself
suggests that in Iran the right to attaining a nuclear bomb may have become
sacred. But one complication is that all of the above ideas provide people with
material benefits: universal welfare was designed deliberately to appeal to the
self-interest of the middle class whilst serving the working class. The NHS
ensures that people are treated according to need – not ability to pay. As for
aid and carbon reduction targets, while they actually increase cost in the
short-term, and while most of their benefits seem to go to other countries or
future generations, they have often been sold on the premise that they will
create long-term benefits: in terms of aid, preventing violent extremism and
increasing trade; in terms of carbon reduction, increased health, resource
independence, and job-creation. It is therefore difficult to know why people
“believe” in aid and carbon reduction.
Another complication is that
the world of policy is never as simple as that of research. Atran works out
what ideas count as sacred simply by asking people whether they would give
those ideas up in the face of any benefit or cost. But people are never
presented with a simple choice such as “would you give up your belief in the
NHS for an increase in your earnings of 20% a year”; or “would you maintain
your belief in the NHS at a possible decrease in your earnings of 20% a year”.
Although some polling and focus groups take place before most policies are
decided, for the most part taxes are introduced to us not as questions but as
statements. But this limitation itself brings about a new possibility for
gauging whether or not beliefs are sacred.
For Durkheim sacred beliefs
are totems by which societies understand themselves. When those totems come
under threat, society erupts into protests or riots (Cladis 2001). We can
therefore gauge whether ideas are sacred according to whether their coming
under threat induces protest or riot. But Durkheim had in mind concepts rather
than ideas with tangible benefits. So again, because the ideas we are looking
at seem to provide material benefits, the reasons for rioting appear
instrumental. If we look at the protests across Europe in response to cuts, it
seemed to be for the most part people affected by those cuts out on the street.
Common sense would suggest that people do not riot over reductions in foreign
aid either because foreign aid is of no tangible advantage to those at home or
because the victims are not present at hand. On the other hand, people do
undertake (often violent) protest on account of the environment at great cost
to and with few tangible advantages for the protestors. Perhaps then, we
require this double qualification: that to count as sacred, ideas must be both
non-instrumental and capable of inducing large, collective reactions.
From what has been discussed
so far though, football seems to be sacred. As any football fan knows, the
police have long regulated exits from games so as to avoid groups of fans
fighting over something completely non-instrumental. Roger Caillois and George
Bataille think the sacred must more deeply reflect the way a society
understands itself (Caillois 2001; Bataille 1985). A football team adequately
represents the way that the football fans understand themselves, and its appeal
can be quantitatively impressive; many who have travelled to parts of the
Middle East and Africa will have met locals as fanatic about Manchester United
as Mancunians themselves. But football is qualitatively limited in its ability
to represent the way we understand ourselves as a society.
If Adam Dinham’s previous
work is anything to go by, his reasoning for welfare’s being a sacred totem
might rely on something similar to Caillois and Bataille’s understanding of the
sacred. In his Faiths, Public Policy and
Civil Society, Dinham offers an extensive account of how government came to
take on public service and welfare provision from the church over the course of
the 20th century (2009). Now given this process on its own it is
conceivable that government welfare provision might slowly become a sacred
totem by which UK society understood itself and its covenant with government.
But coinciding as this process did with shifts towards secular belief, the idea
that the government - and specifically not the church - provided welfare may
have reinforced this totem. This story would seem to give a much more nuanced
and therefore convincing account of how just one idea might become sacred. It
seems to rely on something similar to Caillois and Bataille’s approach because
it implies that an idea must broadly represent the way that a society perceives
itself in order to be sacred for that society.
This nuanced approach is
useful for two reasons: it gives us an idea of when and how something becomes
sacred; and it gives us insight into how complicated the process is. Dinham
considers the NHS in the same history of how government came to take on public
services. But can we consider foreign aid or carbon reduction in a similar way?
As with public services, government has displaced the church as the major
provide of foreign aid. Yet for the reasons already suggested foreign aid is
less emotive.
Since carbon reduction has
proved to be non-instrumental and collective and has always been led by
business or government, it remains the special case. We must therefore
interrogate where its sacred elements might have come from if we are to agree
it has such elements. The obvious place to turn is the green movement. In his Green Politics is Eutopian, Paul Gillk explains how the green
movement arose as a spiritual response to ideas of civilization (2008).
In order to explain how this
response was spiritual, it is worth leaning on Nietzsche’s reflections
concerning how to cultivate a sense of the sacred in human activities.
Nietzsche was particularly interested in how religions engage the whole person:
diet, ritual, thought (1990). Picking up on how these reflections might be
relevant for ostensibly nonreligious activities, Bataille thought of how the
military and avante-garde groups similarly looked to engage the whole person (Bataille
1985). With this in mind, it is worth reflecting that the green movement was
not just about government reform but also about collective self-reform. I bring
about a change in the way I live my life in the hope that others will do their
bit and follow my lead.
So perhaps what makes all of
these ideas special is that they are underpinned in some way by ideas that are
non-instrumental and collective. The trajectory of how each idea came to be
sacred differs. This might explain why some ideas seem more sacred than others.
While some ideas, like the NHS, seem almost indestructible, we are told that
people’s interest in the environment is proportionate to the health of the
economy. Perhaps then, the sacred
is a spectrum, and how sacred an idea is will tell us something about how much
of a burden people are willing to carry in its name.
Author
Timothy Stacey
Works Cited
Atran, Scott, Talking to the Enemy, HarperCollins,
London, 2010
Bataille, George, Visions of Excess (trans. Allan Stoekl),
University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis, 1985
Caillois, Roger, Man and the Sacred (trans. Meyer
Barash), University of Illinois Press, Champaign, 2001
Cladis, Mark, ‘Introduction’
to Elementary Forms of Religious Life,
Oxford UP, Oxford, 2001
Dinham, Adam, Faiths, Public Policy and Civil Society,
Palgrave Macmillan, London, 2009
(a . d i n h a m [at] g o
l d. a c . u k), (14 March 2012), RE: Sorry new copy, [online]. Email to
Timothy Stacey (t I m o t h y j s t a c e y [at] g m a i l . c o m).
Gillk, Paul, Green Politics is Eutopian, Lutterworth Press, Cambridge, 2008
Nietzsche, Friedrich, Beyond Good and Evil (trans. R.J.
Hollingdale), Penguin, London, 1990
Purnell, James, interviewed
by: Jeremy Paxman, Newsnight, BBC2,
21st March 2012, 22:30
Stacey, Timothy, (2012) What Counts as Sacred? College of Sociology,
[online], Available from:
<http://collegeofsociology.blogspot.co.uk/2012/03/what-counts-as-sacred-message-from.html>
[Accessed 26 March 2012].
No comments:
Post a Comment